

출처: Block Media
Federal Reserve Faces Pushback as Governor Myron Urges Steep Rate Reductions
Stephen Myron, the newest member of the Federal Reserve’s Board of Governors and former chief economic adviser during the Trump administration, has sparked debate with his proposal for an aggressive, 2-percentage-point cut to interest rates. While his arguments for the policy shift draw on the playbook of Trump-era economics, they have been met with widespread skepticism from Wall Street and economic experts alike.
Critics have questioned both the validity and timing of Myron’s recommendation, with many suggesting that his proposal disregards current economic realities and market dynamics.
Myron’s Case for Aggressive Monetary Easing
Myron argues that the Federal Funds rate, which currently sits within a range of 4–4.25%, is unnecessarily high. He insists it should be lowered to 2.5%, citing the purported success of Trump administration policies—including restrictive immigration measures, reductions in government borrowing, and deregulation of major industries. Myron, a long-time advocate of low interest rates and protectionist trade tariffs, links these structural policies to a reduction in long-term real interest rates.
To bolster his case, Myron utilizes the Taylor Rule, a widely-adopted economic model for determining optimal interest rates relative to inflation and economic output. According to his interpretation, the current economic situation warrants much lower rates. Myron’s confidence in this approach reflects his broader alignment with the fundamentals of supply-side economics that defined Trump-era strategies.
Real-World Complexities Challenge Myron's Framework
Despite Myron’s steadfast rationale, economic experts and policymakers have flagged significant flaws in his reasoning. A central theme in Myron's argument is the belief that restrictive immigration policies reduce investment demand and, in turn, lower the natural long-term rate of interest. Critics, however, contend that such policies often lead to unexpected economic side effects—including labor shortages and upward wage pressures—that can actually fuel inflation rather than suppress it.
On fiscal policy, Myron’s assertions regarding government borrowing cuts and tariffs as revenue generation mechanisms appear overly simplistic. For example, tariffs imposed during the Trump era were often side-stepped by businesses rerouting supply chains or diversifying import sources, which diminished their long-term fiscal impact. Furthermore, contradictory measures, such as interventions to prevent the nationalization of specific corporations like Intel, muddle the narrative of a purely deregulatory approach that Myron frequently champions.
Market Dynamics Do Not Align with Myron’s Predictions
A deeper analysis of market performance undercuts Myron’s call for drastic monetary easing. The U.S. economy continues to show robust annual growth exceeding 3%. At the same time, stock markets, bond yields, and commodity prices (including gold) all remain strong, signaling resilience in the face of current rate levels. Loan demand, an essential metric for gauging consumer and corporate confidence, has also remained steady, providing little evidence that the current interest rates are stifling economic activities.
Concerns over unemployment have emerged, but these have been counterbalanced by recent inflationary trends, which make the case for expansive monetary easing appear less compelling. Even Myron’s own acknowledgments regarding factors like investments in artificial intelligence and restructured supply chains suggest an environment where the neutral rate—or "r-star"—has naturally risen, further challenging his argument for immediate rate cuts.
If Myron’s proposed rate slash were implemented, bond prices would likely rally by over 10%, the U.S. dollar would weaken considerably, and equity markets could see a further surge. However, current market indicators do not reflect anticipation of such dramatic shifts, signaling investor skepticism about both the feasibility and necessity of such a policy move.
A Question of Timing and Justification
Even if some elements of Myron’s policy framework hold merit in a theoretical or long-term sense, economic analysts have questioned its relevance under current conditions. The macroeconomic environment—a blend of solid growth, tame unemployment, and manageable inflation—does not support an urgent need for aggressive monetary easing.
The prevailing consensus among policymakers and financial markets is that the Federal Reserve’s current interest rate strategy is appropriately calibrated to sustain economic stability. Myron’s claim that sharp rate cuts are necessary has failed to persuade either the boardrooms or the trading floors of Wall Street. Moreover, the incomplete and contradictory results of Trump-era economic policies cast further doubt on the underlying rationale for his approach.
Conclusion
While Myron’s advocacy for dramatic interest rate reductions reflects his broader ideological allegiance to the policies of the Trump administration, his arguments appear disconnected from the complexities of the current economic landscape. Investors and experts overwhelmingly view his proposal as untimely and impractical, and questions linger over its long-term legitimacy.
As it stands, Myron’s bold stance remains a polarizing voice within the Federal Reserve, unlikely to sway a cautious policymaking consensus that prioritizes economic stability over politically tinged recommendations. Until clearer evidence emerges to substantiate his claims, his proposal may remain just that—a theory with limited real-world traction.